References Arrow, K.J. (1962). The economics implication of learning by doing. The Review of Economic Studies, 29(3), 155-173. Ben-David, D., Papell, D.H. (1998). Slowdowns and meltdowns: Postwar growth evidence from 74 countries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(4), 561-571. Barro, R., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (2004). Economic growth (2nd Ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Bernanke, B.S. (1983). Nonmonetary effect of the financial crisis in the propagation of the great depression, The American Economic Review, 73(3), 257-276. Blaug, M. (1979). Economic theory in retrospect. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Calvo, G.A. (1998). Capital flows and capital-market crises: The simple economics of sudden stops. Journal of Applied Economics, 1(1), 35-54. Catling, H. (1970). The spinning mule. Newton Abbot: David and Charles. Chandler, A.D., Jr. (1990). Scale and scope: The dynamics of industrial capitalism. Cambridge: Belknap Press. Chari, V.V., Kehoe, P.J., McGrattan, E.R. (2005). Sudden stops and output drops. American Economic Review, 95(2), 381-387. Chenery, H.B., Robinson, S. and Syrquin, M. (1986). Industrialization and growth: A comparative study. New York: Oxford University Press. Clapham, J.H. (1926-1938). An economic history of modern Britain (1st Ed.). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Clark, G. (2007). A farewell to alms: A brief economic history of the world, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Crafts, N.F.R., Mills, T.C. (1997). Endogenous innovation, trend growth, and the British Industrial Revolution: Reply to Greasley and Oxley. The Journal of Economic History, 57(4), 950-956. Deane, P. (1979). The first industrial revolution (2nd Ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Debertin, D.L. (1986). Agricultural production economics. New York: MacMillan. Dornbusch, R., Goldfajn, I., Valdes, R.O. (1995). Currency crises and collapses. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1995(2), 219-293. Ernst, D. (2001). Global production networks and industrial upgrading: A knowledge-centered approach. East-West Center Working Papers 25. Gras, N.S.B. (1939). Business and capitalism: An introduction to business history. New York: F.S. Crofts. Grossman, G.M., Helpman, E. (1971). Quality ladders in the theory of growth. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(1), 43-61. Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E.E. (1991). Quality ladders in the theory of growth. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(1), 43-61. Hammond, J.L. (1925). The rise of modern industry. London: Mathuen and Co. Ltd. Hausmann, R., Pretchett, L., Rodrik, D., (2005). Growth accelerations. Journal of Economic Growth, 10, 303-329. Hayami, Y., Ruttan, V. (1970). Factor Prices and Technical Change in Agricultural Development: The United States and Japan, 1880-1960. Journal of Political Economy, 78(5), 1115-1141. Heston, A., Summers R., Aten, B. (2002) Penn World Table Version 6.1. Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP). Hobson, J.A. (1965). The evolution of modern capitalism: A study of machine production. London: Walter Scott. Hoffman, W.G. (1958). The growth of industrial economics, trans. Henderson, W.O. and Chaloner, W. H.. Manchester, UK: Manchester University Press. Jackson, R.V. (1992). Rate of industrial growth during the Industrial Revolution. Economic History Review, 45(1), 1-23. Jalee, P. (1977). How capitalism works. New York: New York University Press. John, A.H. (1961). Aspects of English economic growth in the first half of the eighteenth century. Economica, New Series, 28(110), 176-190. John, A.H. (1965). Agricultural productivity and economic growth in England, 1700-1760. Journal of Economic History, 26(1), 19-34. Kaldor, N. (1978). Cases of the slow rate of economic growth of the United Kingdom. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Original published in 1966) Kim, T., Heshmati, A., Park, J. (Forthcoming). Decelerating agricultural society: Theoretical and historical perspectives. Technological Forecasting & Social Change. Knowles, L.C.A. (1924). The industrial and commercial revolution in Great Britain during the 19th Century. London: Routledge. Kremer, M. (1993). Population growth and technological change: One million B.C. to 1990. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 180(3), 681-716. Lewis, A.W. (1955). The theory of economic growth. London: Unwin Hyman. Maddison, A. (1982). Phase of capitalist development. New York: Oxford University Press. Maddison, A. (1995). Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 44 National Accounts. Maddison, A. (2001). The world economy: A millennial perspective. Paris: Development Center of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of economics (8th ed.). London: Macmillan and Co., Ltd. Masi, D. (1987). L'avvento post-industriale. Milano: Franco Angeli. Mitchell, B.R. & Dean, P. (1962). Abstract of British historical statistics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Mokyr, J. (2000). The Industrial Revolution and the Netherlands: Why did it not happen? De Economist, 148(4), 503-520. Myrdal, G. (1957). Economic theory and underdeveloped regions. London: Gerald Duckworth. Norton, J.A., Bass F.M. (1987). A diffusion theory model of adoption and substitution for successive generations of high-technology products. Management Science, 33(9), 1069-1086. OECD Development Centre (2001). The world economy: A millennial perspective. Paris, France. OECD Development Centre (2003). The world economy: Historical statistics. Paris, France. Peneder, M. (2001). Entrepreneurial competition and industrial location: Investigating the structural patterns and intangible sources of competitive performance. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. Perron, P. (1989). The great crash, the oil price shock and the unit root hypothesis, Econometrica 58, 1361-1401. Pollard, S. (1965). The genesis of modern management: A Study of the Industrial Revolution in Great Britain. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Pomeranz, K. (2000). The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world economy. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Romer, D. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 71-102. Ruttan, V.W. (2001). Technology, growth, and development: an induced innovation perspective. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. Salvadori, N., & Panico, C. (2006). Classical, neoclassical and Keynesian views on growth and distribution. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. Schumpeter, J.A. (1939). Business cycles: A theoretical, historical and statistical analysis of the capitalist process. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company. Shiller, R.J. (2008). The subprime solution: How today's global financial crisis happened, and what to do about it. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Smelser, N.J. (1959). Social change in the industrial revolution: An application of theory to the Lancashire cotton industry 1770-1840. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Smith, A. (1776). The wealth of nations. Edited by Edwin Cannan, 1904. Reprint edition 1937. New York: Modern Library. Solow, R.M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 39(3), 312-320. Stanley D.C. (1970). Fixed capital formation in the British cotton industry, 1770-1815. Economic History Review, 23(2), 263-266. Stavenhagen, R. (1982). Problemas etnicos y campesinos. Mexico: Instituto Nacional de Indigenistas. Stiglitz, J. (2003). What I learned at the world economic crisis, globalization and the poor: Exploitation or equalizer? New York: International Debate Education Association. Sutton, J. (1991). Sunk costs and market structure: Price competition, advertising, and the evolution of concentration. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Vries, J. de (2000). Dutch economic growth in comparative-historical perspective, 1500-2000. De Economist, 148(4), 443-467. Wilson, C. (1957). The Entrepreneur in the Industrial Revolution in Britain. History, 42(145), 101-117. Wrigley, E.A. (1989). Continuity, chance and change: The character of the Industrial Revolution in England. Cambridge & New York: Cambridge UP.