References [1] Acs, Z. J., D. B. Audretsch (1987). “Innovation, Market Structure and Firm Size,” Review of Economics and Statistics 69: 567-575. [2] Bauer, J. M. (2007). “Dynamic effects of network neutrality,” International Journal of Communication 1: 531-547. [3] de Bijl, P., M. Peitz (2008). “Innovation, convergence and the role of regulation in the Netherlands and beyond,” Telecommunications Policy 32(11): 744-754. [4] Cambini, C., Y. Jiang (2009). “Broadband investment and regulation: A literature review,” Telecommunications Policy 33: 559-574. [5] Carlton, D. W., M. Waldman (2002). “The strategic use of tying to preserve and create market power in evolving industries,” Rand Journal of Economics 32(2): 194-220. [6] Cheng, H. K., S. Bandyopadhyay, H. Guo (2011). “The debate on net neutrality: A policy perspective,” Information Systems Research, 22(1): 60-82. [7] Choi, J.-P., B.-C. Kim (2010). “Net neutrality and investment incentives,” Rand Journal of Economics 41(3): 446-471. [8] Christodoulou, K., Vlahous, K. (2001). “Implications of regulation for entry and investment in the local loop,” Telecommunications Policy 25(10-11): 743-757. [9] Clarke, R. (2009). “Costs of neutral/unmanaged IP networks,” Review of Network Economics 8: 61-89. [10] Cohen, W. M., R. C. Levin, D. C. Mowery (1987). “Firm size and R&D intensity: A re-examination?” Journal of Industrial Economics 35: 543-563. [11] Crandall, R., H. Singer (2003). “An accurate scorecard of the Telecommunications Act of 1996: Rejoinder to the Phoenix Center Study No.7,” Report by Criterion Economics, Washington, DC. [12] Crowcroft, J. (2007). “Net neutrality: The technical side of the debate—A white paper,” International Journal of Communication 1: 567-579. [13] Dhamdhere, A., C. Dovrolis (2008). “Can ISPs be profitable without violating ‘network neutrality’?” In applications, technologies, architectures, and protocols for computer communication,” Proceedings of the 3rd International Workshop on Economics of Networked Systems, NetEcon’08, August 22, 2008, Seattle, Washington, USA. [14] Economides, N. (2010). “Why Imposing New Tolls on Third-Party Content and Applications Threatens Innovation and Will Not Improve Broadband Providers’ Investment,” Appendix A in Comments of Google Inc., FCC GN Dkt. 09-191; WC Dkt.: 07-52. [15] Economides, N., J. Tag (2009). “Net neutrality on the Internet: A two-sided market analysis,” unpublished manuscript, New York University and the Research Institute of Industrial Economics. [16] Edquist, C. (1997). Systems of Innovation-Technologies, Institutions and Organizations, London: Pinter Publishers. [17] Evans, D. S. 2003. “The antitrust economics of multi-sided platform markets,” Yale Journal on Regulation 20: 325-382. [18] Farrell, J. P., P. J. Weiser (2003). “Modularity, vertical integration, and open access policies: Towards a convergence of antitrust and regulation in the Internet age,” Harvard Journal of Law and Technology 17(1): 13-21. [19] Federal Communications Commission (2009). Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, (FCC NPRM), Docket No. GN 09-93. [20] Ford, G. S., T. M. Koutsky, L. J. Spiwak (2007), “Network neutrality and industry structure,” Hastings Communications and Entertainment Law 29: 149-156. [21] Frieden, R. (2006). “Network neutrality or bias? Handicapping the odds for a tiered and branded Internet,” Hastings Communications and Enterprise Law Journal 29: 171-216. [22] Frischmann, B. M., B. van Schewick (2007). “Network neutrality and the economics of an information superhighway: A reply to Professor Yoo,” Jurimetrics 47: 383-428. [23] Freeman, C. (1982). The Economics of Industrial Innovation, 2nd edition, Frances Pinter, London. [24] Freeman, C. (2002). “Continental, national and sub-national innovation systems-complementarity and economic growth,” Research Policy 31(2): 191-211. [25] Ganley, P., B. Allgrove (2006). “Net neutrality: A user’s guide,” Computer Law & Security Report 22(6): 454-463. [26] Guo, H., S. Bandyopadhyay, H. K. Cheng, Y. C. Yang (2010). “Net neutrality and vertical integration of content and broadband services,” Journal of Management Information Systems 27(2): 243-275. [27] Hahn, R., S. Wallsten (2006). “The Economics of Net Neutrality,” Working Paper no. RP06-13, AEI-Brookings Joint Center, 2006. Available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=943757Hagiu, A. 2006. “Proprietary vs. Open Two-Sided Platforms and Social Efficiency.” Forthcoming, Working Paper, AEI-Brookings Joint Center. [28] Hermalin, B. E., M. L. Katz (2007). “The economics of product-line restrictions with an application to the network neutrality debate,” Information Economics and Policy 19: 215-248. [29] Hogendorn, C. (2007). “Broadband Internet: Net neutrality versus open access,” IEEP 4: 185-208. [30] Hogendorn, C. (2010). Spillovers and Network Neutrality. Regulation and the Performance of Communication and Information Networks, Gerry Faulhaber, Gary Madden, Jeffrey Petchey, eds., Edward Elgar, Forthcoming. Available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1632491. [31] Ingraham, A., G. Sidak (2003). “Mandatory unbundling, UNE-P, and the cost of equity: Does TELRIC pricing increase risk for incumbent local exchange carriers?” Yale Journal on Regulation 20: 389-406. [32] Jordan, S. (2007). “A layered network approach to net neutrality,” International Journal of Communication 1: 427-460. [33] Jordan, S. (2009). “A layered United States universal service fund for an everything-over-IP World,” Telecommunications Policy 33(3-4): 111-128. [34] Jordan, S., A. Ghosh (2009). “How to determine whether a traffic management practice is reasonable,” Research Conference on Communication, Information and Internet Policy (TPRC), Arlington, Virginia, September 2009. [35] Jorde, T., G. Sidak, D. Teece. (2000). “Innovation, investment and unbundling,” Yale Journal on Regulation 17(1): 1-37. [36] Kamien, M. I., N. L. Schwartz (1982). Market Structure and Innovation, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. [37] Kocsis, V., P. W. J. de Bijl (2007). “Network neutrality and the nature of competition between network operators,” International Economics and Economic Policy 4(2): 159-184. [38] Laffont, J., J. Tirole (2000). Competition in Telecommunications. Cambridge: MIT Press. [39] Lee, R., T. Wu (2009). “Subsidizing creativity through network design: Zero-pricing and net neutrality,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 23(3): 61-76. [40] Lessig, L. (2006a). Testimony before the Senate Committee on Commerce, Science and Transportation Hearing on “Network Neutrality,” February 7, 2006. Available at http://commerce.senate.gov/hearings/witnesslist.cfm?id=1705. [41] Lessig, L. (2006b). “Testimony of Larry Lessig, Hearing on Network Neutrality,” Senate Committee on Commerce, Science and Transportation, 2006. [42] Levinson, D. (2009). “Network neutrality: Lessons from transportation,” Review of Network Economics 8: 13-21. [43] Lundvall, B. A. (1992). National Systems of Innovation: Towards a Theory of Innovation and Interactive Learning, London: Pinter Publishers. [44] Lundvall, B. A., B. Johnson, E. S. Andersen, B. Dalum (2002). “National systems of production, innovation and competence building,” Research Policy 31(2): 213-231. [45] Malerba, F., L. Orsenigo (1995). “Schumpeterian patterns of innovation,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 19: 47-65. [46] Malerba, F., L. Orsenigo (1996). “Schumpeterian patterns of innovation are technology-specific,” Research Policy 25: 451-478. [47] Malerba, F. (2002). “Sectoral Systems of Innovation Production,” Research Policy 31(2): 247-264. [48] Musacchio, J., G. Schwartz, J. Walrand (2007). “Network neutrality and provider investment incentives,” Asolomar Conference on Signals, Systems and Computers. [49] Musacchio, J., G. Schwartz, J. Walrand (2009). “A two-sided market analysis of provider investment incentives with an application to the net-neutrality issue,” Review of Network Economics 8(1): 22-39. [50] Nelson, R. R., N. Rosenberg (1993). “Technical Innovation and National Systems” in Nelson, R. R. (ed.) (1993). National Innovation Systems-A Comparative Analysis, Oxford: Oxford University Press. [51] Odlyzko, A. (2009). “Network neutrality, search neutrality, and the never-ending conflict between efficiency and fairness in markets,” Review of Network Economics 8(1): 40-60. [52] OECD (2006). “Network Neutrality: A Policy Overview,” DSTI/ICCP/TISP(2006)4. [53] OECD (2007). Internet Traffic Prioritisation: An Overview, DSTI/ICCP/TISP(2006)4/FINAL. [54] Patel, P., K. Pavitt (1994). “The nature and economic importance of national innovations systems,” STI Review, OECD, 9-30. [55] Pavitt, K. (1984). “Sectoral patterns of technical change: Towards a taxonomy and a theory,” Research Policy 13: 343-373. [56] Pavitt, K., M. Robinson, J. Townsend (1987). “The size distribution of innovating firms in the UK: 1945-1983,” Journal of Industrial Economics 35: 297-316. [57] Peha, J. (2007). “The benefits and risks of mandating network neutrality, and the quest for a balanced policy,” International Journal of Communication 1: 644-668. [58] Phoenix Center Policy Bulletin No.5 (2003). Competition and Bell Company investment in telecommunications plant: the effects of UNE-P. Available at: http:// www.phoenix-center.org/PolicyBulletin/PolicyBulletin5.pdf. [59] Phoenix Center Policy Bulletin No.6 (2003). UNE-P drives Bell investment: a synthesis model. Available at: http://www.phoenix-center.org/PolicyBulletin/ PolicyBulletin5.pdf. [60] Posner, R. A. (2001). Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective, University of Chicago Press, 2nd edition. [61] Rey, P., J. Tirole (2007).”A primeron foreclosure,” in M. Armstrong and R. Porter, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, volume 3, North Holland: Elsevier, 2145-2220. [62] Rochet, J.-C., J. Tirole. (2003). “Platform competition in two-sided markets,” Journal of the European Economic Association 1(4): 990-1029. [63] Rothwell, R., W. Zegveld (1982). Innovation and Small and Medium Sized Firm, London: Frances Pinter. [64] Roycroft, T. R. (2006). “Economic analysis and network neutrality: Separating empirical facts from theoretical fiction,” Consumer Federation of America, Consumers Union and Free Press: 4-16. [65] Rubinfeld, D., H. Singer (2001). “Vertical foreclosure in broadband access?” Journal of Industrial Economics 59(3): 299-318. [66] Scherer, F. M., K. Huh (1992). “R&D reactions to high-technology import competition,” Review of Economics and Statistics 74: 202-212. [67] Schuett, F. (2010). “Network neutrality: A survey of the economic literature,” Review of Network Economics 9(2): 1-13. [68] Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Economic Studies. [69] Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy, New York: Harper. [70] Shrimali, G. (2008). “Surplus extraction by network providers: Implications for net neutrality and innovation,” Telecommunications Policy 32(8): 545-558. [71] Sidak, J. G. (2006). “A consumer-welfare approach to network neutrality regulation of the Internet,” Journal of Competition Law and Economics 2(3): 349-474. [72] Soete, L. (1979). “Firm size and innovative activity: The evidence reconsidered,” European Economic Review 12: 319-340. [73] Speta, J. B. (2000a). “Handicapping the race for the last mile? A critique of open access rules for broadband platforms,” Yale Journal on Regulation 17: 39-91. [74] Speta, J. B. (2000b). “The vertical dimension of cable open access,” University of Colorado Law Review 71: 975-1010. [75] Speta, J. B. (2009). “A sensible next step on network neutrality: The market power question,” Review of Network Economics 8(1): 113-127. [76] Thierer, A. (2005). “Are ‘dumb pipe’ mandates smart public policy? Vertical integration, net neutrality, and the Network Layers Model,” Journal on Telecommunications & High Technology Law 3: 275-308. [77] Turner, D. (2009). Finding the Bottom Line: The Truth about Network Neutrality and Investment, Free Press, www.freepress.net. [78] van Schewick, B. (2007). “Towards an economic framework for network neutrality regulation,” Journal on Telecommunications and High Technology Law 5(2): 329-391. [79] Whinston, M. D. (1990). “Tying, foreclosure, and exclusion,” American Economic Review 80(4): 837-859. [80] Willig, R. (2006). Investment is appropriately stimulated by TELRIC. Princeton University. Available at http://psc.ky.gov/pscecf/2003-00379/5200700_efs/04132004/MCI_ST_MTB_EX_14_04%2013%2004.pdf. [81] Wallsten, S., S. Hausladen (2009). “Net neutrality, unbundling, and their effects on international investment in next-generation networks,” Review of Network Economics 8(1): 90-112. [82] Wu, T. (2003). “Network neutrality, broadband discrimination,” Journal of Telecommunications and High Technology Law 2: 141-178. [83] Wu, T. (2004). “The broadband debate: A user’s guide,” Telecommunications and High Technology Law 3: 69-96. [84] Wu, T., C. S. Yoo (2007). “Keeping the Internet neutral? Tim Wu and Christopher Yoo debate.” Federal Communications Law Journal 59(3): 575-592. [85] Yoo, C. S. (2004). “Would mandating broadband network neutrality help or hurt competition? A comment on the end-to-end debate,” Journal of Telecommunications and High Technology Law 3. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=495502. [86] Yoo, C. S. (2005). “Beyond network neutrality,” Harvard Journal of Law & Technology 19(1): 1-77. [87] Yoo, C. S. (2006a). “Network neutrality and the economics of congestion,” Georgetown Law 94: 21-27. [88] Yoo, C. S. (2006b). Promoting Broadband through Network Diversity. White Paper. Nashville, TN: Vanderbilt University Law School: 56. [89] Zarakas, W., G. Woroch, L. Wood, D. McFadden, N. Ilias, P. Liu (2005). Structural simulation of facility sharing: unbundling policies and investment strategy in local exchange markets. Report by The Brattle Group, Washington, DC. Available at http://www.brattle.com/_documents/UploadLibrary/ ArticleReport2347.pdf. [90] Zhu, K. (2007). “Bringing neutrality to network neutrality,” Berkeley Technology Law Journal 22: 615-645.